Page - (000059) - in Disrupted Development and the Future of Inequality in the Age of Automation
Image of the Page - (000059) -
Text of the Page - (000059) -
52 L. SCHLOGL AND A. SUMNER
limited even in upper middle-income developing countries. Compared
to advanced high-income countries, they have a larger agricultural
sector, and lower employment and value-added shares in industry and
manufacturing, as well as a large informal service sector again not only in
the world’s poorest countries but even in upper middle-income countries.
Production in such economies is less capital-intensive and productivity
levels are thus lower than in high-income countries.
A number of developing countries have substantially shifted economic
value-added activity from agriculture and resources to manufacturing
and service sectors. For developing countries with such characteristics,
a set of questions arises in the context of automation (that are differ-
ent to the world’s very poorest countries): What if industrial production
can increasingly be carried out with minimal human labor input? What
if robots in high-income countries start to compete with cheap labor?
Is it plausible that there could be a disintegration of global value chains
via “reshoring,” i.e. the repatriation of formerly outsourced production
to high-income countries? What if the service sector—where currently
the largest share of labor is absorbed in many middle-income develop-
ing countries—goes through dramatic shifts of labor productivity, thanks
to innovations in software and AI? Does automation exacerbate a much-
debated “middle-income trap” if it exists at all and thus impede catch-up
development? Are there new sectors of economic activity emerging
which promise decent employment opportunities for large popula-
tions rather than economic growth accompanied by weak employment
growth? These questions point toward the importance of situating the
role of technology in broader theories of economic development.
5.2 disrupted development? the role
of technologicAl chAnge in long-run
economic development
The neoclassical standard model of growth attributes a key role to techno-
logical change in long-run economic growth. In the Solow (1956) model,
growth can be achieved either via an increase in the inputs of production,
e.g. an expansion of the labor force or an increase in the capital intensity,
or it can happen via greater efficiency in the combination of inputs that
generates a larger output. The latter route is known as the dynamics of
total factor productivity (TFP) and innovation in automation technologies
is generally considered an important factor in raising the TFP.
Disrupted Development and the Future of Inequality in the Age of Automation